Skip to main content
xYOU DESERVE INDEPENDENT, CRITICAL MEDIA. We want readers like you. Support independent critical media.

Economy Sliding into Serious Stagnation but Modi & Co are Clueless

Reviving the economy requires, apart from social peace, a powerful fiscal intervention going well beyond what neo-liberalism allows.
Economy Sliding into Serious Stagnation

Changes in estimation methods have of late made statistics on the Indian economy increasingly bewildering; besides, whenever the statistics show the performance of the economy in a poor light, the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) government simply suppresses them. Nothing, however, can suppress the fact that the Indian economy is sliding into a serious state of stagnation.

The third quarter (October-December) GDP (gross domestic product) estimates which have just been released show a 4.7% growth over the corresponding quarter last year, which comes on the heels of a 4.5% growth in the second quarter. The National Statistical Office (NSO) now believes that the growth rate for the fiscal year 2019-20 will be no more than 5%. Various financial agencies put the figure even lower.

Even if we take 5%, that will still be an 11-year low. In addition, it is by now quite clear that the new method of GDP estimation seriously overestimates its growth rate; in fact a former Chief Economic Advisor had suggested that against the 7% growth which was being claimed for the period before the slowdown began, the actual growth rate would have been only around 4.5%. This means that even the 5% official growth rate projected for 1919-20 would actually entail a much lower growth rate, no more perhaps than 3 to 3.5%, which in the old days used to be facetiously called the “Hindu Rate of Growth”.

The ascendancy of the Hindutva forces, it would appear, has even “Hinduised” the rate of growth! But there are some important differences between this 3.5% growth and that of the old days, of which at least three must be noted.

First, the 3.5% GDP growth rate of the earlier period was accompanied by much higher rates of employment growth, because those days there were restraints upon the introduction of labour-displacing technological-cum-structural change.

Second, the inequality in income distribution is increasing these days unlike then. In fact, as Piketty and Chancel have estimated on the basis of income tax data that the share of the top 1% of households in total income had become as low as 6% in the early 1980s; it has climbed thereafter to about 22% in 2013-14, which is the highest it has ever been since 1922 when income tax was first introduced in India.

Third, the overall growth rate then was sustained by a significant growth rate in agriculture, especially foodgrains, so that per capita foodgrain output and availability increased noticeably, reversing a trend that had come to characterise the last half-century of colonial rule. The per capita availability had fallen from about 200 kilograms around 1900 to less than 140 kilograms at Independence (1947); it increased to about 180 kilograms by the end of the 1980s and has again fallen since then.

In other words, despite the GDP growth in the pre-liberalisation period being relatively small, it was more evenly distributed, and alleviated hunger to a far greater extent, than during the heyday of neo-liberalism, let alone at present when we are witnessing a slowdown in growth.

The slower growth in 2019-20 than in 2018-19 (for which it has been estimated at 6.1%) is mainly due to a slowdown in non-agricultural growth. In the agriculture sector, the growth rate in 2019-20 is expected to be about the same as in the previous year, 2.9% compared with 2.88%, which is small but steady. Elsewhere, however, growth has slowed down and is expected to bring down the overall rate to 5%. What is particularly striking is the slowing down of industrial growth, especially of the manufacturing sector.

The government expects industrial growth to be around 2% in 2019-20 and judging by the fact that both in the second and the third quarters of 2019-20 there have been actually negative growth rates, even 2% seems a tall order. The slowing down of industrial growth in the face of an apparently unchanging growth rate in agriculture is intriguing at first sight, but there are three basic reasons for this.

First, the growth-rate of agriculture is not the same as the growth rate of rural consumer expenditure. Even when the growth rate of agriculture is high, the growth rate of rural consumption expenditure appears sluggish. The classic example of this was in 2017-18, which was a bumper crop year, and yet, according to National Sample Survey data, per capita real expenditure in rural India was absolutely lower in that year compared with 2011-12 by as much as 8%. This could be partly because of infirmities in agricultural growth estimates; but, more importantly, it is because the cost-of-living index for peasants and agricultural labourers is grossly underestimated, as it does not take into account the cost-raising effects of the privatisation of essential services, such as education and healthcare.

Second, in a neo-liberal economy, the role of the external market increases greatly compared with the home market, as the latter is kept deliberately restricted, as a consequence of keeping down wages for the sake of improving international competitiveness. This provides the means by which the world economic crisis impacts on the level of activity in the Indian economy. The growth of exports has indeed slowed down which, in turn, has had multiplier effects on the economy as a whole, including on the industrial sector.

A peculiarity of the Indian economy must be noted here. By opening itself to global commodity and capital flows, India did manage to increase its exports of a number of service sector products, especially IT-related services. But as far as the industrial sector was concerned, “openness” hardly had any net benefits for the Indian economy; on the contrary, it might have had a net negative effect. Indeed, the rate of industrial growth during the entire neo-liberal period was no higher than during the dirigiste period.

While Indian industry found it difficult to stand up to East Asian, especially Chinese, competition in the domestic market, it could not make much headway in the export market either. “Opening up”, in other words, had the effect of keeping industrial growth suppressed, even as it stimulated certain services. With the world economy entering into a period of slowdown owing to the dead-end reached by neo-liberalism, this industrial repression has turned into a retrogression, even as the stimulation of the service sector has come to an end, pushing the economy into a prolonged period of stagnation.

This is where the third factor for industrial stagnation becomes operative, which relates to a cut back in investment. The capital goods sector has been particularly badly hit by the stagnation because of this cutback, which is both a cause and a consequence of the industrial stagnation.

The BJP government, needless to say, has no clue about how to revive the economy. Its corporate tax cuts predictably have not made an iota of difference to private corporate investment. Since such investment responds to the expected growth of the market, as long as the growth of the market is not accelerated, there would hardly be any higher investment, no matter how much taxes are cut. On the contrary, if such cuts lead to a reduction in government expenditure (for meeting the fiscal deficit target), then capacity utilisation will fall, and so will private corporate investment because of such cuts.

Its other measures, like tinkering with goods and services tax rates and the “Make in India” campaign, are equally flawed. Such tinkering will not help; and if it leads to lower revenues and hence lower expenditures (again for meeting the fiscal deficit target), then it will be counter-productive.

As for “Make in India”, when not much investment is being undertaken anyway because of the world economic crisis, there is little hope of getting much investment into India. And the pogrom against Muslims, not to mention the general social unrest generated by the Citizenship Amendment Act and National Register of Citizens, will drive such investment away rather than attracting it into India.

We are, in short, saddled with a serious economic stagnation, whose overcoming requires, apart from social peace, a powerful fiscal intervention going well beyond what neo-liberalism allows. Modi and company, alas, have little idea of it. And all this is without taking into account the impact of the coronavirus on the world economy.

Get the latest reports & analysis with people's perspective on Protests, movements & deep analytical videos, discussions of the current affairs in your Telegram app. Subscribe to NewsClick's Telegram channel & get Real-Time updates on stories, as they get published on our website.

Subscribe Newsclick On Telegram

Latest